Changes
Jump to navigation
Jump to search
Baron (2001) - Theories of Strategic Nonmarket Participation (view source)
Revision as of 21:30, 29 October 2009
, 21:30, 29 October 2009→Vote Recruitment in Client Politics
A slightly simplified version of the model used now follows.
===Legislators and Interests===
Legislators have ideal points: <math>z \backsim U \left [ - \frac{1}{2},\frac{1}{2} \right ]</math> with the median legislator's ideal point denoted <math>\, z_m = 0</math>.
:<math>\quad U \left( w , z \right ) = -\alpha(w-z) + r_w, \quad \alpha>0</math> where <math>\, \alpha</math> represents the intensity of preferences.
The Interest seeks <math>x > 0,\quad x \ge y</math> where <math>\, y</math> is the status quo and the Agenda is <math>\, A=\{x,y\}</math>.
A necessary condition for nonmarket action is that <math>\frac{(x+y)}{2} > z_m \,</math>.
We can also consider the indifferent voter <math>z_i</math> and note that this votes will be inactive if <math>z_i \le z_m </math> and active if <math>\, z_i > z_m</math>.
===Resource Provision===
A legislator has an absolute-value policy plus resource contribution based utility function. That is a legislator will vote for <math>x</math> over <math>y</math> iif:
:Case 3: <math>x \le z: \quad r_x=-\alpha (x-y)</math> obtained by noting that both of the absolute values are negative and rearranging.
===Making Legislators Indifferent===
For simplicity consider the case where <math>z_m < y < \frac{x+y}{2} </math>. Putting these points on a line divides the line into four regions. The resource provision required to make a legislator indifferent in each region is:
Note that the legislators with ideal points <math>z_m > \frac{x+y}{2}</math> always vote for the interest's policy and there is no need to contribute resources to them. Likewise in it unnecessary to contribute to legislators below the median, at least if there is no uncertainty of types and a majority rule is in place (etc). Further more the resources needed are decreasing in <math>z</math> for <math>z \in (z_m,\frac{x+y}{2}]</math>, so interests must provide more resources to more strongly opposed legislators, and are strictly increasing in <math>x</math>.
===Total Resources===
The total resources required are:
:<math>R = \int_0^{\frac{x+y}{2}} r^*</math>
In the case where <math>y > 0\,</math>:
:<math>\quad r^*=\frac{\alpha}{4}\left ( x+y \right )^2 - \alpha y^2</math>
In the case where <math>y \le 0\,</math>:
:<math> \quad r^*=\frac{\alpha}{4}\left ( x+y \right )^2</math>
===Recruiting Votes===
Now suppose that the interest has a utility function described by:
:<math>U_g(w,z_g) = =\beta (w - z_g)^2 -R(x,y)\,, \quad</math>
where<math>z_g \ge x\,</math> is the interest's ideal point and <math>\beta > 0\,</math> is the strength of the interest's preferences.
For <math>y \le 0\,</math>, the interest will recruit votes iff:
:<math>z_g \ge z_g^+(x,y) \equiv \frac{x+y}{2} \left (1+\frac{\alpha(x+y)^2}{4 \beta (x-y)}\right) - \frac{\alpha y^2}{2 \beta (x-y)}</math>
===Comparative Statics===
A crucial contribution of this model is that it allows some basic comparative statics. Examination of the effects of changes in exogenous parameters for the case where <math>y \le 0\,</math> shows that: