Changes
Jump to navigation
Jump to search
PTLR Up Group Processed BibTeX (view source)
Revision as of 18:35, 25 March 2013
, 18:35, 25 March 2013no edit summary
year={2011},
publisher={FrancoAngeli Editore},
abstract={Inventors and users of technology often enter into cooperative agreements for sharing their intellectual property in order to implement a standard or to avoid costly litigation. Over the past two decades, U.S. antitrust authorities have viewed pooling arrangements that integrate complementary, valid and essential patents as having procompetitive benefits in reducing prices, transactions costs, and the incidence of legal suits. Since patent pools are cooperative agreements, they also have the potential of suppressing competition if, for example, they harbor weak or invalid patents, dampen incentives to conduct research on innovations that compete with the pooled patents, foreclose competition from downstream product or upstream input markets, or raise prices on goods that compete with the pooled patents. In synthesizing the ideas advanced in the economic literature, this paper explores whether these antitrust concerns apply to pools with complementary patents and, if they do, the implications for competition policy to constrain them. Special attention is given to the application of the U.S. Department of Justice‐Federal Justice-Federal Trade Commission Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (1995) and its companion Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition (2007) to recent patent pool cases.},
discipline={Econ},
research_type={Theory},
industry={Biotechnology},
thicket_stance={Weak Pro},
thicket_stance_extract={The strength of the anti‐commons anti-commons thesis rests on two assumptions that are very difficult to test: (1) that developing commercial biomedical products requires access to many different IP rights and (2) that negotiating access with different patent owners is prohibitively difficult and costly. On the first point, the number of biotechnology patents has certainly increased dramatically over the last decade, although by itself that does not necessarily imply greater fragmentation. Walsh et al. (2003) report from interviews with biotechnology industry IP practitioners that preliminary freedom to operate searches can sometimes find hundreds of patents relevant to a candidate product but that on closer inspection “there may be, in a complicated case, about 6‐12 6-12 that they have to seriously address, but that more typically the number was zero.” Enough anecdotal evidence exists, however, to suggest that the fragmentation of rights in biotechnology is sometimes a serious concern.},
thicket_def={Def32},
thicket_def_extract={The IP rights situation described above was arguably a classical case of a patent thicket with fragmented IP rights and uncertainty about technology ownership},
filename={Lanjouw Schankerman (2004) - Protecting Intellectual Property Rights Are Small Firms Handicapped.pdf}
}
@article{layne2011join, title={To join or not to join: examining patent pool participation and rent sharing rules}, author={Layne-Farrar, Anne and Lerner, Josh}, journal={International Journal of Industrial Organization}, volume={29}, number={2}, pages={294--303}, year={2011}, abstract={In recognition that participation in modern patent pools is voluntary, we present empirical evidence on participation rates and the factors that drive the decision to join a pool, including the pro?t sharing rules adopted by the pool's founders. In most participation contexts, the at-risk group is extremely dif?cult, if not impossible, to identify. For pools centered on technologies that result from a standard-setting process, in contrast, we are able to identify a relatively unambiguous population of patents eligible for inclusion but that have not been included in the pool. We ?nd that vertically integrated ?rms, with patents and downstream operations, are more likely to join a patent pool and among those ?rms that do join, those with relatively symmetric patent contributions (in terms of value) to a standard appear more likely to accept numeric patent share rules for dividing royalty earnings}, discipline={Mgmt}, research_type={Empirical}, industry={}, thicket_stance={}, thicket_stance_extract={}, thicket_def={}, thicket_def_extract={}, tags={}, filename={LayneFarrar Lerner (2011) - To Join Or Not To Join.pdf} }
@article{leaffer2009patent,
title={Patent Misuse and Innovation},
tags={Pools},
filename={Lerner Strojwas Tirole (2003) - The Structure And Performance Of Patent Pools Empirical Evidence.pdf}
}
@techreport{lerner2003cooperative,
title={Cooperative marketing agreements between competitors: evidence from patent pools},
author={Lerner, Josh and Tirole, Jean and Strojwas, Marcin},
year={2003},
institution={National Bureau of Economic Research} abstract={On numerous occasions, rival firms seek to market goods together, particularly in hightechnology industries. This paper empirically examines one such institution: the patent pool. The analysis highlights five findings consistent with the theoretical predictions: (a) pools involving substitute patents are unlikely to allow pool members to license patents independently, consistent with our earlier theoretical work; (b) independent licensing is more frequently allowed when the number of members in the pool grows, which may reflect the increasing challenges that reconciling users’ differing technological agendas pose in large pools; (c) larger pools are more likely to have centralized control of litigation, which may reflect either the fact that the incentives for individual enforcement in large pools are smaller or that large pools are more likely to include small players with limited enforcement capabilities; (d) third party licensing is more common in larger pools, consistent with suggestions that such pools were established primarily to resolve the bargaining difficulties posed by overlapping patent holdings; and (e) during the most recent era, when an intense awareness of antitrust concerns precluded many competitionharming patent pools, more important patents were selected for pools and patents selected for pools were subsequently more intensively referenced by others. },
discipline={Econ},
research_type={Discussion},
industry={},
thicket_stance={},
thicket_stance_extract={},
thicket_def={},
thicket_def_extract={},
tags={},
filename={Lerner Tirole Strojwas (2003) - Cooperative Marketing Agreements Between Competitors.pdf}
}
@article{lerner2007design,
title={The design of patent pools: The determinants of licensing rules},
author={Lerner, Josh and Strojwas, Marcin and Tirole, Jean},
journal={The RAND Journal of Economics},
volume={38},
number={3},
pages={610--625},
year={2007},
abstract={Patent pools are an important but little-studied economic institution. In this article, we first make a set of predictions about the licensing terms associated with patent pools. The theoretical framework predicts that (i) pools consisting of complementary patents are more likely to allow members to engage in independent licensing and (ii) the requirement that firms license patents to the pool (grantbacks) should be associated with pools that consist of complements and allow independent licensing. We then examine the terms of 63 pools, and show that licensing rules are consistent with these hypotheses. },
discipline={Econ},
research_type={Theory},
industry={},
thicket_stance={},
thicket_stance_extract={},
thicket_def={},
thicket_def_extract={},
tags={},
filename={Lerner Strojwas Tirole (2007) - The Design Of Patent Pools The Determinants Of Licensing Rules.pdf}
}
@techreport{lerner2002efficient,
title={Efficient Patent Pools},
industry={General},
thicket_stance={Weak Pro},
thicket_stance_extract={Innovations in computer hardware, software, and biotechnology often build on a number of other innovations owned by a diverse set of owners and as a result patent ?patent thicket" problems - overlapping patent claims that preclude the adoption of new technologies - can be severe.},
thicket_def={def40},
thicket_def_extract={Innovations in computer hardware, software, and biotechnology often build on a number of other innovations owned by a diverse set of owners and as a result patent ?patent thicket" problems - overlapping patent claims that preclude the adoption of new technologies - can be severe.},
tags={Patent pools, welfare},
filename={Lerner Tirole (2002) - Efficient Patent Pools.pdf}
pages={1125--1139},
year={2008},
abstract={The patent system was initially designed to provide incentives to develop stand-alone innovations in fi
elds fi?elds such as mechanics, chemicals or pharmaceuticals. Its application is therefore problematical in more recent
elds ?elds such as biotechnology and ICT industries, where innovation patterns are different. A well-known problem concerns cumulative innovations. Patent law must then trade off the rights granted to upstream patent owners with the incentives to develop subsequent innovations (Scotchmer, 1991; Donoghue, Scotchmer and Thisse, 1998; Denicolò, 2000). Another issue concerns complementary innovations, which are the focus of the paper. When
final ?final products embody several complementary innovations, the scattering of patents between various owners jeopardizes the commercial exploitation of the products because of negotiation and royalty stacking issues (Merges & Nelson, 1990; Heller & Eisenberg, 1998; Shapiro, 2001). In biotechnology, this is the case of therapeutic proteins or genetic diagnostic tests that require the use of multiple patented gene fragments (Heller & Eisenberg, 1998). It is also very frequent in ICT industries such as electronics, computer hardware and software, where
firms ?firms have to navigate "patent thickets" (Shapiro, 2001). Shapiro (2001) reports, for example, that in the semi-conductor industry
rms ?rms receive thousands ?thousands of patents each year and manufacturers can potentially infringe on hundreds of patents with a single product". The situation is similar in the U.S. software industry, where there are potentially ?potentially dozens or hundreds of patents covering individual components of a productproduct?(FTC, 2003). I study the problem of the production of complementary innovations in a model of dynamic R&D competition between two
firms?firms, and argue that in some cases complementary innovations should not be patentable as such, but bundled with other innovations prior to patenting. To do so I consider two complementary innovations and examine whether they should be patented separately or as a bundle. This approach echoes several papers on cumulative innovations where patentability requirements are de
ned de?ned as the need to develop two or more successive innovations before obtaining a patent (Scotchmer and Green, 1990; Hunt, 1995; ODonoghueO?Donoghue, Scotchmer and Thisse, 1998; Denicolò, 2000). As regards complementary innovations, the optimal patenting rule depends on a trade-off between the pro
fit pro?fit loss due to scattered complementary patents, and the possible bene
fit bene?fit of patent disclosure. The scattering of complementary patents between different owners creates a double marginalization issue. Since each patentee behaves as a monopolist, the Cournot (1838) theorem predicts that prices do not maximize the
rmspro
ts ?rms?pro?ts (Shapiro, 2001; Lerner & Tirole, 2005)1 . The requirement that complementary innovations be bundled prior to patenting can be a way to prevent this pro
t pro?t loss. However, small innovations are not disclosed when innovations have to be bundled prior to patenting (Scotchmer and Green, 1990). As a result,
firms ?firms lose the possibility to quit the race after a
first ?first innovation has been patented, which leads to R&D cost duplications. I show that patent disclosure has a positive social effect, although it does not permit a fully effi cient coordination between
firms?firms. In this context, bundling innovations prior to patenting can be more effi cient if innovations can be devel- oped quickly. As I argue in the Conclusion, this condition is consistent with the legal de
nition de?nition of the "inventive step" patentability requirement. The paper is structured in six sections. First, the model is introduced in Section 2. Section 3 then considers the case in which innovations can be patented separately, while Section 4 focuses on the case in which they must be bundled prior to patenting. Section 5 compares the social outcomes of the two require- ments. Finally, Section 6 concludes and discusses the policy implications of the model.},
discipline={Econ},
research_type={Theory},
industry={ICT, Biotechnology},
thicket_stance={Assumed Pro},
thicket_stance_extract={The present paper upholds policy arguments that emphasize the importance of a severe application of this patentability requirement as a means to limit the size of "patent thickets" and to promote innovation in sectors where complementary innovations are frequent (Jaffe, 2000; Barton, 2003; FTC, 2003)... When
final ?final products embody several complementary innovations, the scattering of patents between various owners jeopardizes the commercial exploitation of the products because of negotiation and royalty stacking issues (Merges & Nelson, 1990; Heller & Eisenberg, 1998; Shapiro, 2001)},
thicket_def={def1},
thicket_def_extract={It is also very frequent in ICT industries such as electronics, computer hardware and software, where
rms ?rms have to navigate "patent thickets" (Shapiro, 2001).},
tags={Patent disclosure, bundling and separate patents, },
filename={Meniere (2008) - Patent Law And Complementary Innovations.pdf}
tags={patent pools},
filename={Santore McKee Bjornstad (2010) - Patent Pools As A Solution To Efficient Licensing Of Complementary Patents.pdf}
}
@article{schmidt2007negotiating,
title={Negotiating the RNAi Patent Thicket},
author={Schmidt, C.},
journal={Nature biotechnology},
volume={25},
number={3},
pages={273--280},
year={2007},
publisher={New York, NY: Nature Pub. Co., 1996-},
abstract={Patent disputes haven’t materialized in the RNAi field yet, but once products near the market, it might be a different story. Charlie Schmidt investigates.},
discipline={Biology},
research_type={Discussion},
industry={Biology},
thicket_stance={},
thicket_stance_extract={},
thicket_def={},
thicket_def_extract={},
tags={RNA Interface, Licensing, Royalties},
filename={Schmidt (2007) - Negotiating The Rnai Patent Thicket.pdf}
}
pages={1348--1364},
year={2008},
abstract={This paper studies the behaviour of
firms ?firms facing the decision to create a patent fence, de
fined de?fined as a portfolio of substitute patents. We set up a patent race model, where
firms ?firms can decide either to patent their inventions, or to rely on secrecy. It is shown that fi
rms fi?rms build patent fences, when the duopoly profi
ts profi?ts net of R&D costs are positive. We also demonstrate that in this context, a fi
rm fi?rm will rely on secrecy when the speed of discovery of the subsequent invention is high compared to the competitorscompetitor?s. Furthermore, we compare the model under the First-to-Invent and First-to-File legal rules. Finally, we analyze the welfare implications of patent fences.},
discipline={Econ},
research_type={Theory},
thicket_stance_extract={While the issue of "thickets" of complementary technologies in cumulative innovations has been extensively analyzed2, as well as the institutional solutions to overcome this problem (Lerner and Tirole, 2005 and Shapiro, 2001), little attention has been paid to fencing patents so far.},
thicket_def={def10},
thicket_def_extract={More precisely,
firms ?firms will patent a coherent group of inventions, which form what is sometimes called a patent "bulk", aimed at protecting one product. The "bulk" can either be a "fence" of substitute patents or a "thicket" of complementary patents (see Reitzig, 2004 and Cohen et al., 2000).},
tags={patent fences, },
filename={Schneider (2008) - Fences And Competition In Patent Races.pdf}
filename={Shand Wetter (2007) - Trends In Intellectual Property And Nanotechnology.pdf}
}
@article{schmidt2007negotiatingsiebert2006licensing, title={Negotiating the RNAi Patent ThicketHow licensing resolves hold-up: Evidence from a dynamic panel data model with unobserved heterogeneity}, author={SchmidtSiebert, C.}, journal={Nature biotechnology}, volume={25}, number={3}Ralph and Von Graevenitz, pages={273--280Georg}, year={2007}, publisher={New York, NY: Nature Pub. Co., 1996-2006}, abstract={Patent disputes haven’t materialized in the RNAi field yet, but once products near the market, it might be a different story. Charlie Schmidt investigates.}, discipline={Biology}, research_type={Discussion}, industry={Biology},
thicket_stance={},
thicket_stance_extract={},
thicket_def={},
thicket_def_extract={},
tags={RNA Interface}, Licensing, Royalties} , filename={Schmidt Siebert VonGraevenitz (20072006) - Negotiating The Rnai Patent ThicketHow Licensing Resolves Hold Up.pdf}
}
@article{somaya2003strategic,
title = {Strategic Determinants of Decisions Not to Settle Patent Litigation},