Difference between revisions of "Romer, T. and H. Rosenthal (1978), Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas and the Status Quo"
(3 intermediate revisions by one other user not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{Article | {{Article | ||
|Has page=Romer, T. and H. Rosenthal (1978), Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas and the Status Quo | |Has page=Romer, T. and H. Rosenthal (1978), Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas and the Status Quo | ||
− | |Has title= | + | |Has bibtex key= |
− | |Has author= | + | |Has article title=Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas and the Status Quo |
− | |Has year= | + | |Has author=Romer, T. and H. Rosenthal |
+ | |Has year=1978 | ||
|In journal= | |In journal= | ||
|In volume= | |In volume= |
Latest revision as of 18:15, 29 September 2020
Article | |
---|---|
Has bibtex key | |
Has article title | Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas and the Status Quo |
Has author | Romer, T. and H. Rosenthal |
Has year | 1978 |
In journal | |
In volume | |
In number | |
Has pages | |
Has publisher | |
© edegan.com, 2016 |
Back to BPP Field Exam Papers 2012
Background
Committees allow for division of labor and gains from specialization. However, a committee also has gate keeping power. If gates kept closed, the status quo prevails. If gates opened, the policy outcome depends on if open or closed rule is use.
Open Rule
If committee opens gates, legislators propose policies to challenge status quo. Simply majority voting selects Condorcet winner [math]x_{m}[/math]. Committee only opens gate if he prefers [math]x_{m}[/math] to [math]x_{0}[/math] the status quo.
Suppose [math]x_{0} \lt x_{c} \lt x_{m}[/math]. We can see that the median of the committee prefers [math]x_{0}[/math] to [math]x_{m}[/math], so he will keep the gates closed and not allow a vote, as voting will result in [math]x_{m}[/math]. Thus, we get a status quo bias under open rule.
Closed Rule
The closed rule solves these types of commitment problems.