Difference between revisions of "Shepsle, K. (1979), Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models"
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{Article | {{Article | ||
|Has page=Shepsle, K. (1979), Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models | |Has page=Shepsle, K. (1979), Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models | ||
− | |Has title= | + | |Has title=Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models |
|Has author= | |Has author= | ||
|Has year= | |Has year= |
Revision as of 12:13, 29 September 2020
Article | |
---|---|
Has bibtex key | |
Has article title | |
Has year | |
In journal | |
In volume | |
In number | |
Has pages | |
Has publisher | |
© edegan.com, 2016 |
Back to BPP Field Exam Papers 2012
Paper's Motivation
McKelvey's Chaos Thm: In a multidimensional spacial settings, unless points are distributed in a rare way (like radially symmetric), there is no Condorcet winner, and whoever controls the order of voting can make any point the final outcome.
In response, the author considers voting on one 'attribute' or dimension at a time.
Model
Consider a two-dimensional case. Any policy [math]z_{i}[/math] is characterized by coordinates [math](x_i, y_i)[/math].
Result
In first stage we vote on [math]x_{i}[/math]. and obtain policy equal to median voters bliss point [math]x_{m}[/math]. In second stage we vote on [math]y_i[/math] and obtain policy equal to median voters bliss point [math]y_m[/math], so we obtain unique outcome [math]z=(x_m, y_m)[/math]. Notice, that with this sequential voting, we do not get the median policy, but the median policy by dimension.