Difference between revisions of "Grossman Helpman (2001) - Special Interest Politics Chapters 4 And 5"
imported>Ed |
imported>Ed |
||
Line 147: | Line 147: | ||
#As <math>\delta\,</math> gets smaller, more partitions can be sustained. | #As <math>\delta\,</math> gets smaller, more partitions can be sustained. | ||
#If <math>n\,</math> partitions can be sustained then so can <math>k<n\,</math>. | #If <math>n\,</math> partitions can be sustained then so can <math>k<n\,</math>. | ||
+ | |||
===Welfare considerations=== | ===Welfare considerations=== | ||
More partitions are more informative and yield greater welfare. The equilibrium with the greatest number of partitions is the one preferred by both the SIG and the policymaker. | More partitions are more informative and yield greater welfare. The equilibrium with the greatest number of partitions is the one preferred by both the SIG and the policymaker. | ||
+ | |||
===Two Lobbies - Like bias=== | ===Two Lobbies - Like bias=== | ||
Line 166: | Line 168: | ||
====Public Meetings==== | ====Public Meetings==== | ||
− | When information is reported sequentially there can not be full relevation. There can be a partition equilibrium from combining the two reports. | + | When information is reported sequentially there can not be full relevation. There can be a partition equilibrium from combining the two reports. The number of partitions can not be greater than the number that would arise from a single lobby with the smaller (more moderate) bias, and so both would agree to allow only this SIG to report. |
+ | |||
+ | |||
+ | ===Two Lobbies - Opposite Bias=== | ||
+ | |||
+ | With two lobbies where <math>\delta_1 < 0\,</math> and <math>\delta_2 > 0 \,</math> the policy maker can use the competition to become more informed, though not fully informed. | ||
+ | |||
+ | Crucially, define \theta_2^* \equiv \theta_{max} - \delta_2 | ||
+ | |||
+ | It is not possible to reveal the state of the world when \theta > \theta_2^*. See the paper for further information. | ||
+ | |||
+ | |||
+ | ===Multi-dimensional Information=== | ||
+ | |||
+ | When the groups differ in their relative bias on a single dimension there is full revelation. By choosing new dimensions through the multidimensional space it is possible (given the necessary dimensionality of the choices and alignment conditions) to establish full relevation through-out the space. |
Revision as of 18:57, 27 April 2010
- This page is referenced in BPP Field Exam Papers
Contents
Reference(s)
Grossman, Gene and Elhanan Helpman (2001), "Special Interest Politics", Chapters 4 and 5, MIT Press pdf
These chapters reference:
- Crawford, Vincent P. and Joel Sobel (1982), "Strategic Information Transmission", Econometrica, Vol. 50, No. 6 (Nov.), pp. 1431-1451 pdf
- Krishna, Vijay and John Morgan (2001), "A Model of Expertise", The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 116, No. 2 (May), pp. 747-775 pdf
Abstract
No abstract available - these are book chapters.
Summary
These chapters cover:
- One Lobby
- Two states of the world
- Three states of the world
- Continuous states of the world
- Welfare considerations
- Two Lobbies
- Like Bias
- Opposite Bias
- Multidimensional Information
- More General Lobbying
The Model(s)
In general there is a policy maker who choses a policy to implement [math]p\,[/math], based on some facts about the state of the world [math]\theta\,[/math]. There is also a Special Interest Group (SIG) who observes the facts about the state of the world but has a bias [math]\delta \gt 0\,[/math]. The utility functions of both types of players are inverse quadratic (i.e. quadratic loss functions).
Utility of the policy maker:
- [math]G(p,\theta) = -(p - \theta)^2\,[/math]
Utility of the SIG:
- [math]U(p,\theta) = -(p - \theta - \delta)^2\,[/math]
The policy maker sets [math]p=\theta\,[/math] when the SIG reveals the true state of the world and [math]p=\mathbb{E}\tilde{\theta}\,[/math] otherwise.
One Lobby - Two States
There are two states of the world:
- [math]\theta_H \gt \theta_L\,[/math]
Given that the bias is positive the SIG never has any incentive to misrepresent the high state, that is a report of [math]\theta_H\,[/math] will be trusted by the policy maker who will implement [math]p=\theta_H\,[/math].
Supposing that the true state is [math]\theta_L\,[/math], then we can use the distance from ideal points to see for what levels of bias the SIG will truely report this. Specifically the sig prefers to truthfully report if:
- [math](\theta_L + \delta) - \theta_L \le \theta_H - (\theta_L + \delta)\,[/math]
- [math]\therefore \delta \le \frac{\theta_H - \theta_L}{2}\,[/math]
When the bias satisfies this criteria there is informative lobbying and we can have full relevation, however this is not the sole equilibrium. Suppose the policy maker distrusted the SIG, then the policy maker would implement:
- [math]p=\frac{(\theta_L+\theta_H)}{2}\,[/math]
Knowing this the SIG has no incentive to report truthfully - this is the Babbling Equilibrium and it always exists.
However, there is an equilibrium refinement by Farrel where the SIG makes a speech essentially saying "I have no incentive to lie". The SIG prefers [math]\theta_L\,[/math] to the policy maker's distrust implementation if is closer to his ideal point of [math](\theta_L+\delta)\,[/math]:
- [math](\theta_L+\delta) - \theta_L \le \frac{(\theta_L+\theta_H)}{2} - (\theta_L+\delta)\,[/math]
- [math]\therefore \delta \lt \frac{(\theta_H- \theta_L)}{4}\,[/math] provides the criteria for not trusting the SIG.
One Lobby - Three States
Again there is no incentive for the SIG to misreport [math]\theta_H\,[/math] when it is the true state. When [math]\theta_M\,[/math] is the true state we can perform the bias restriction calculation as before to get:
- [math]\delta \le \frac{\theta_H-\theta_M}{2}\,[/math]
If we were just distinguishing between all three states this would hold for [math]\theta_L\,[/math] too:
- [math]\delta \le \frac{\theta_M-\theta_L}{2}\,[/math]
However, the SIG now has the option of reporting [math]\theta_L\,[/math] or not [math]\theta_L\,[/math], in the latter case expecting the policy maker to implement [math]\frac{(\theta_H-\theta_M)}{2}\,[/math]. In this case of partial information transmission we have to recalculate the bias restriction for when the real state of the world is [math]\theta_L\,[/math] (For [math]\theta_M\,[/math] the bias restriction is less binding). Here the SIG's ideal point is [math]\theta_L+\delta\,[/math] so the SIG will not report falsely iff:
- [math](\theta_L+\delta) - \theta_L \ge \frac{(\theta_H + \theta_M)}{2} - (\theta_L + \delta)\,[/math]
- [math]\therefore \delta \le \frac{\theta_H - \theta_M}{4} + {\theta_M - \theta_L}{2}\,[/math]
This allows for an equilibrium with partial transmission of information - this can be possible when the bias conditions for full transmission are violated.
One Lobby - Continuous States
As the number of states grows it becomes harder to get full relevation - the bias must be less than half of the distance between two states and this tends to zero as the number of states tends towards infinity. However, we can partition a continuous range of information and report credible with range the true state of the world falls in.
Suppose that:
- [math]\tilde{\theta} \sim U[\theta_{min},\theta_{max}]\,[/math]
The SIG then reports [math]\theta_1\,[/math] if [math]\theta_{min} \le \theta \le \theta_1\,[/math] and so forth. The policy maker getting such a report implements [math]\frac{(\theta_{min} + \theta_1)}{2}\,[/math]. The temptation to lie is greatest when [math]\theta\,[/math] is on the boundary of [math]\theta_1\,[/math], and [math]\theta_2\,[/math] is the greatest temptation (all other higher values greater exagerate the outcome and will overshoot the bliss point). Credibility therefore requires:
- [math]\frac{(\theta_1 + \theta_2)}{2} - (\theta_1 + \delta) \ge (\theta_1 + \delta) - \frac{(\theta_{min} + \theta_1)}{2}\,[/math]
This solves to:
- [math]\theta_2 \ge 2\theta_1 +4\delta - \theta_{min}\,[/math]
If the truth is in [math]\theta_2\,[/math], then the SIG would prefer to report this rather than [math]\theta_1\,[/math] iif:
- [math](\theta_2 + \delta) - \frac{(\theta_1 + \theta_2)}{2} \le (\theta_1 + \delta) - \frac{(\theta_{min} + \theta_1)}{2}\,[/math]
This solves to:
- [math]\theta_2 \le 2\theta_1 +4\delta - \theta_{min}\,[/math]
Putting these two together we have that:
- [math]\theta_2 = 2\theta_1 +4\delta - \theta_{min}\,[/math]
More generally, as these equations have to hold for each and every interval:
- [math]\theta_j = 2\theta_{j-1} +4\delta - \theta_{j-2}\,[/math]
There are two boundaries where [math]\theta_n = \theta_{max}\,[/math] and [math]\theta_0 = \theta_{min}\,[/math], which can be used together to solve the general solutions for [math]\theta_j\,[/math]:
- [math]\theta_j = \frac{j}{n}\theta_{max} +\frac{n-j}{n}\theta_{min} -j(n-j)\delta\,[/math]
Considering that [math]\theta_1 \gt \theta_{min}\,[/math] it must be the case that:
- [math]2n(n-1)\delta \lt \theta_{max} - \theta_{min}\,[/math]
There are some things to note:
- Partitions get bigger to the right
- There always exists an equilibrium with [math]n=1\,[/math] - it is the babbling equilibrium
- As [math]\delta\,[/math] gets smaller, more partitions can be sustained.
- If [math]n\,[/math] partitions can be sustained then so can [math]k\lt n\,[/math].
Welfare considerations
More partitions are more informative and yield greater welfare. The equilibrium with the greatest number of partitions is the one preferred by both the SIG and the policymaker.
Two Lobbies - Like bias
Suppose that [math]0 \lt \delta_1 \le \delta_2\,[/math] so that SIG 1 is more moderate. There are three cases to consider: secret meetings, private meetings and public meetings. With secret meetings the SIGs do not know if the other SIG has met with the policy maker, and with private meetings they know the meeting has taken place but do not know the contents.
Secret Meetings
The SIGs behave as if they alone are providing information and the policy maker combines informations. The combined information is more informative, but there is no actual equilibrium (because of the implicit assumption of no strategic response).
Private Meetings
Using each SIG to discipline the other, the policy maker can gain full relevation. However, this is a fragile equilibrium.
Public Meetings
When information is reported sequentially there can not be full relevation. There can be a partition equilibrium from combining the two reports. The number of partitions can not be greater than the number that would arise from a single lobby with the smaller (more moderate) bias, and so both would agree to allow only this SIG to report.
Two Lobbies - Opposite Bias
With two lobbies where [math]\delta_1 \lt 0\,[/math] and [math]\delta_2 \gt 0 \,[/math] the policy maker can use the competition to become more informed, though not fully informed.
Crucially, define \theta_2^* \equiv \theta_{max} - \delta_2
It is not possible to reveal the state of the world when \theta > \theta_2^*. See the paper for further information.
Multi-dimensional Information
When the groups differ in their relative bias on a single dimension there is full revelation. By choosing new dimensions through the multidimensional space it is possible (given the necessary dimensionality of the choices and alignment conditions) to establish full relevation through-out the space.